We expect far more political choice today than we used to in the past.
Parties aren't just expected to balance the budget - there's a whole range of smaller issues that we expect to know about before we vote for them.
This is all having an unforeseen effects, as this column explores . . .
ONE OF THESE AND TWO OF THOSE
Blame the big department stores,
if you like. They were based on two simple, revolutionary, ideas, which caught
on in a big way. Firstly, the prices were fixed. There was no haggling. It
didn’t matter who you were or how much money could be gouged out of your
pockets; everybody paid the same price. Secondly, the stores carried a wide
range of merchandise and a shopper could choose between different suppliers of
the same article: be it a dress or a shoe. Previously, shops could just keep
stocking the same item until it had all been sold, because choice was
arbitrarily limited. Suddenly, the balance between the consumer and
manufacturer changed dramatically in the purchaser’s favour. The customer could
choose. They could buy what they wanted, not just what someone
else was offering them.
Eventually, this transformed the
economy. It’s taken time but today, everyone’s empowered. The ramifications of
this change in influence are still working their way through society, but
they’ve arrived politically.
The change began in a small way.
Fifty years ago we voted for political parties that would run the country
harnessing advice from public servants and government boards. Choice was
limited. There were a few attempts to challenge the general, complacent
consensus (such as NSW Premier Jack Lang’s attempt, during the depression, to
repudiate debt or Labor Prime Minister Ben Chifley’s crack at nationalising
banks after World War Two) but basically, voters left it up to the parties to both
determine policies and how they should be implemented.
If you want to point to one
individual who’s responsible for the increased expectations voters have about
economic debate, it would probably be Paul Keating. As Treasurer, he set out to
‘educate’ the electorate about the effect of economic policy. He set up
white-boards and graphs in his office and brought-in senior public servants in
to brief journalists, to bring them (and hence the public) ‘on-board’.
Suddenly, people realised governments could be empowered to make real changes.
That’s when it started to go
kaput for the politicians. As the recession of the early ‘90’s gripped the
country, economists began to hit the airwaves with their own prescriptions for
government. Those who were elected had to explain government spending. Today, for
example, failing to balance the books has become a ‘no-no’. Kevin Rudd briefly
got away with the stimulating the economy to avoid recession, however the
minute the direst threat was avoided the incessant demand to ‘balance the
budget’ started up again. The Gonski review into higher education never
attempted to justify extra spending on the grounds that knowledge is
intrinsically good: instead the argument was put that any extra spending would
provide an immediate pay-off. It’s all dollars in and dollars out. Government
reduced to simple economic management, because we don’t trust the politicians
to do anything else.
And this is the central stumbling
block when it comes to reconciling the magnificent aims with the limited
resources to be devoted to the National Disability Insurance Scheme. Nobody
prominent appears prepared to say we don’t need such a scheme (Campbell Newman,
as Premier of Queensland, is self-evidently not prominent in the
sense of being a significant contributor to national debate – after all, he
personally decided to opt out). Considerable questions remain, however, about
how the NDIS will eventually be rolled out and who’s going to fund it.
The point is that in order to be
worthwhile the scheme will need to receive an injection of new money. That’s cash
that comes from somewhere else. And this is the problem. You can get some idea
of just how insurmountable an issue it is when you go to the bottom line. The
first hiccup came with the trial. Two Liberal state premiers were holding out
until, following a massive public outcry, they searched in their pockets and,
goodness! Suddenly they found they did have the money after all!
That gets us over the first
hurdle – funding the pilot. The problem is the track stretches way off into the
distance and there’s no simple way to explain where the money to fund the
program will come from. In NSW, for example, the trial required the state to
put in $585 million, to be matched with another $300 million extra from
Canberra. This will allow the average spend on each disabled person to be
boosted from (just over) $20,000 to (almost) $35,000. Great. But what happens
in 2018, when the scheme’s rolled out nationally?
That’s when the ‘spend’ suddenly
zooms to $7.5 billion a year. That’s a big figure. Most of us have only a vague
idea of what that sort of money can actually buy, so it’s worth putting it in
context. Dealing with asylum seekers, for example, costs just over $1 billion
annually. We devote just under $9 billion to the higher education sector
whereas the yearly cost of operating the Defence Force is, depending on exactly
where it’s fighting, north of $21 billion. The Commonwealth also allocates
slightly more than $61 billion to health, which represents about 16 percent of
the total budget outlay.
So where will the money come
from? Close down universities or sell-off the destroyer fleet? Government
services don’t appear have much fat left to trim. On the other hand, the
capital gains tax exemption for your primary residence ‘costs’ the government
an estimated $20 billion a year. Julia Gillard could easily fund the NDIS (and
have money left over) by simply eliminating a concession that’s disproportionately
benefiting wealthy people (who live in more expensive houses). Somehow, I think
that’s unlikely. The other possibility that’s been floated is increasing the
Medicare levy. Increasing this by just 0.5 percent would cost a typical
taxpayer $5 a week. A cup of coffee. Unfortunately, people have got used to
their beverages and even this would provide less than $3.5 billion. Experience
suggests it’s unlikely the cost of the program would remain capped at under $8
billion.
Nobody’s arguing (at the moment) that
devoting money to a proper NDIS scheme isn’t worthwhile. The problem is finding
the money to sustain it. We’ve become accustomed to seeing price tags on items
for sale in department stores and use these to make a quick mental calculation
before deciding what we can afford. Unless the government can suddenly find
some hollow-log that’s escaped all previous efficiency measures, it appears
unlikely that even the most enthusiastic razor gang will be able to find the
massive extra sum required to fund this program without raising taxes. And
that’s where we begin to have problems.
Everyone feels very positive
about helping the disabled until it starts hurting their hip-pocket. At that
point, unfortunately, things start to change.
But how far does public funding have to stretch to cover all of life's risks ? Does a NDIS mean Australia becomes even more of a nanny welfare state ? Should not additional public funding be directed to other priorities such as an ageing population which remains underfunded despite a range of initiatives over recent years at both Federal and State levels.
ReplyDeleteThis is absolutely the point! Where does the role of government begin and end?
Deleteand the answer is !?
ReplyDelete